Debate “Premios Nobel de Economía 2022. Crisis financieras y el papel de los bancos”

El pasado 11 de octubre se anunció la concesión del Premio Banco Central de Suecia en Ciencias Económicas, en memoria de Alfred Nobel, más comúnmente conocido como Premio Nobel de Economía, a los profesores David Card, Guido Imbens y Joshua Angrist. El jurado reconoce a Card sus “contribuciones empíricas en el campo de la economía del trabajo”, destacando entre ellas la que rebate la idea de que una subida del salario mínimo da lugar a pérdidas de empleo. A Angrist y a Imbens se les premia por sus “contribuciones metodológicas en el análisis de las relaciones causales”, es decir, por desarrollar métodos para extraer conclusiones precisas sobre cuáles son las variables causa y efecto a partir de datos económicos reales. Además de sus contribuciones individuales, la Academia ha valorado el trabajo de los tres laureados en el campo de los llamados “experimentos naturales”, es decir, aquellos que extraen conclusiones de los datos producidos por la economía real, procurando aproximar su rigor al de las investigaciones que parten de experimentos controlados.

La Fundación Ramón Areces en colaboración con la Asociación Española de Economía, organizaron la mesa redonda “Premios Nobel de Economía 2022. Crisis financieras y el papel de los bancos”, en la que participaron Natalia Fabra (UC3M), José Luis Peydró (UPF) y Rafael Repullo (CEMFI).

Puedes ver el vídeo del evento aquí.

European economists for an EU-level gas price cap and gas saving targets

The measures adopted so far by the EU have been insufficient to contain the impact of the gas crisis on firms and households. This column proposes an emergency gas policy package to deal with the crisis that threatens European economies and the security of supply. The proposal combines an EU-wide gas price cap with binding gas-saving targets and a continued strong price incentive for users to cut gas consumption. The authors explain how these three policy measures would work together, enhance credibility, address concerns about implementing a price cap, and could accommodate the needs of different EU member states.

Europe is unique in many ways – rather unfortunately so, in one way to do with energy. No other part of the world imports most of its pipeline and liquefied natural gas (LNG) with contracts that are based on short-term market prices. This has allowed Russia to announce and implement gas supply interruptions to drive up prices and thus revenues on all its gas sales. Russia’s strategy has inflicted even higher costs on EU economies as it has led to higher costs on gas imported from other countries and knock-on price increases in power markets, where electricity prices are often set by the cost of gas-fired generation.

As a result, European consumers are exposed to high and hugely volatile gas and electricity costs, raising affordability concerns for poorer households and survival concerns for energy-intensive companies competing in global markets. Since the Russian invasion of Ukraine, the gas market is being used as part of the overall warfare. Hence, the EU needs to implement a joint robust response to protect gas users from excessive risks while maintaining security of supply for households and industry.

So far, the focus of policymakers has been on national programmes compensating households and industry for cost increases – thereby imposing costs of hundreds of billions of euros for public budgets and leading to tensions between member states with differing funding capacities. Governments have also provided liquidity and guarantee programmes for firms and suppliers to ensure continued trading. This has, however, further escalated prices by incentivising firms to bet on even higher prices without the downside risk – which is born by governments.

Critical emergency measures for the gas sector

We believe that a combination of three elements is essential for a successful response to the gas crisis at the EU scale while also contributing to longer-run environmental objectives:

Binding gas saving targets: Lower gas demand in any EU member state reduces gas scarcity prices and the risk of supply interruptions for all other member states. Gas-saving targets help to internalise these tangible benefits in the decision-making process of member states to ensure the implementation of national information, engagement and advice programmes for gas-saving measures for households and industry. These targets need to be supported by a credible monitoring and governance process to build trust among EU partners, including penalties for countries that fail to comply with the gas-saving targets, especially during periods of Europe-wide gas shortages. Targets should be relaxed only for countries and during periods where the European Regulatory Agency (ACER) identifies that further savings will not benefit the other member states due to infrastructure constraints in pipeline and LNG shipping.

A price cap to avoid excessive gas prices: Demand and net supply of gas are highly inelastic once prices exceed the level at which the power sector and industry have shifted from gas to alternative fossil fuels (coal and oil) and have exhausted their energy efficiency opportunities. Hence, any potential scarcity can quickly escalate market prices. Uncertainty about potential supply remains high (see, for example, the explosion of Nordstream 1 pipelines), and has less to do with market fundamentals than with military conflict. An EU-wide price cap ensures that the effect of such uncertainties on forward markets no longer escalates prices, avoiding further damage to the European economies. Lower gas prices have the additional benefit of reducing the cost of electricity generation and the inframarginal rents for some technologies. Therefore, the gas price limit can also contribute to lowering Europe’s overall rate of inflation – by reducing both gas and electricity prices.

A commitment to retain strong incentives for gas saving: A regulatory gas price limit by itself reduces prices, avoiding the need for financial compensation to consumers, including all the distortions this can create for efficiency or across member states. However, the challenge is ensuring that strong gas-savings incentives are maintained despite the lower prices. One option is for member states to guarantee to all consumers a baseline consumption at the price limit while imposing a higher price for consumption above and below the baseline. This will preserve strong marginal incentives for gas savings. Furthermore, if all member states adopted such an incentive mechanism, then every company and household would be assured that other European actors face similar incentives.

The policy package: Why any one of these elements would not succeed on its own  

Gas saving targets alone may not be sufficiently credible to retain gas prices within acceptable bounds in light of the extreme and continuing developments in gas markets. To discourage any supply disruptions and to moderate risk premia associated with such supply interruptions, it is therefore necessary to complement gas-saving targets with a price limit.

An EU-level price cap that binds will immediately reduce incentives for gas savings and also leave unspecified how scarce gas is to be allocated between different EU member states. Gas saving targets will (i) reduce gas consumption and enhance the incentive to save gas (before the cap becomes binding); and (ii) clarify the allocation of gas between member states in the case of a binding price cap.

Strong measures for gas saving are thus important to reinforce the credibility of the gas savings targets and to limit the role of the price cap. Achieving gas savings at the national level requires – if targets are tight – a variety of programmes and measures at the national level, all of which will be more effective if combined with incentives for short-term gas savings from higher marginal prices. Implementing such pricing structures will be supported at the national level if they are directly linked to the benefits from an EU-wide price limit – and therefore already agreed upon as part of a deal.

The policy package: How potential concerns can be addressed through policy design

Our proposed policy package can address legitimate concerns that are often voiced about price caps.

One concern about a price cap involves circumvention and credibility. Indeed, currently discussed proposals to impose a gas price limit only on exchange-based trading would trigger the unintended (and undesirable) consequence of shifting liquidity to bilateral trades – so-called over-the-counter (OTC) markets. To avoid this, governments would have to regulate all gas trading activities. If they are unwilling or unable to do so, they have to find other means to avoid circumvention.

One option to achieve this makes use of the Transmission System Operators’ (TSOs) imbalance mechanism. The TSOs are responsible for keeping the gas system in balance. So, if there are discrepancies between the gas inflows and deliveries nominated by market participants, TSOs have to buy or sell gas to make up the difference. They then impute the cost on the market participants responsible for the imbalance. The risk of potentially very high imbalance prices encourages all market participants to contract sufficient gas to be in balance. The proposal is for EU governments to mandate TSOs not to acquire imbalance gas above a price limit. This would limit the cost for imbalance gas and make market participants unwilling to sign new gas contracts at prices exceeding that limit. As a result, no supplier will be able to sell above the price limit; hence, they will all have to offer gas below the price limit. A small penalty would be imposed on imbalance prices to ensure that gas producers and utilities still find it attractive to contract bilaterally.

For the market to shift to the lower-price equilibrium, it is critical to ensure the credibility of the TSOs’ commitment not to buy above the price limit. To ensure this, the TSOs need access to additional instruments in case there is insufficient gas supply to meet demand at the price limit. These could involve reverse auctions to unlock additional gas savings from consumers at higher prices, storage options (for clearly constrained timeframes) and, if required, the curtailment of the demand of non-privileged consumers.

A second concern relates to the impact of a price limit on gas-saving incentives. This can nevertheless be avoided through a proper design of retail contracts, exposing consumption above a baseline to high prices (and, symmetrically, rebating any savings below the baseline at high prices). It is well-known to economists that ‘non-linear’ pricing can be used to moderate the overall cost of gas while simultaneously retaining strong gas-saving incentives at the margin. That a practical implementation of this principle is possible has already been recently demonstrated by several European countries with gas price limits that retain short-term gas-saving incentives.

A third concern is that a price limit will reduce gas available to the EU. While there is general agreement that gas production will continue at maximum capacity if the price limit is high enough (e.g. at €50/MWh, thus exceeding any historic price spikes), some actors are concerned that Europe will no longer be able to outcompete Asian countries so as to redirect gas towards the EU. Recent analysis of the IEA Gas Market Report (IEA 2022) shows that LNG was freed up thanks to fuel-shifting from gas to oil and coal in China, Korea, Japan, and India. For this fuel-shifting to be profitable in Asian economies without carbon pricing, gas prices in the range of €50/MWh would have been sufficient. Prices exceeding these levels were typically not passed to final consumers and could thus also not deliver demand reductions in Asia to free up the gas for EU demand. The IEA reports that the extremely high gas prices will likely have resulted in additional demand reductions, primarily in Thailand, Indonesia, and Bangladesh. However, these effects would not be large:  LNG volumes redirected to the EU would represent an estimated 1% of EU demand.

Finally, there is a concern that a gas price limit would violate existing long-term import contracts. Yet, adjusting the TSO imbalance pricing structure as discussed above would retain wholesale price formation. Hence, indexation and contractual obligations would remain unaffected, avoiding any interference with existing or future long-term contracts.

Concluding remarks

The measures adopted so far by the EU have been insufficient to contain the impact of the gas crisis on firms and households. More decisive action is needed. Member states must try to find common ground beyond their recent opposing views on an EU gas price cap. We believe a three-step emergency plan combining (i) an effective regulatory gas price limit with (ii) binding gas-saving targets and (iii) measures that retain short-term gas-saving incentives could be up to this task and also address concerns raised by different member states.

There is much to gain for EU citizens and companies. They would obtain immediate relief and reassurance that everyone is acting together to solve this crisis. It would also save hundreds of billions of euros of public money used for national support programmes for households and industry. Furthermore, clarity that gas prices will remain within acceptable bounds will limit margin calls and counterparty risks, reducing the need for governments to provide guarantees that involve taxpayer risks at the scale of hundreds of billions of euros. While European unity is challenged, member states can choose to act resolutely and show that the EU really means to be stronger together.

Authors: Natalia Fabra,  Karsten Neuhoff, and Nicolas Berghmans.

See the post here.

Podcast EsadeEcPol: “La preocupación por los efectos distributivos debe empapar la transición energética”

La invasión de Ucrania y la consiguiente escalada de los precios del gas y el petróleo han acelerado el cambio en la política energética europea. A los motivos ya existentes para acelerar la transición hacia fuentes no contaminantes, dice en esta entrevista Natalia Fabra, catedrática del departamento de Economía en la Universidad Carlos III, añadimos los problemas de seguridad.

En este episodio de “El Futuro de las Ideas”, Ramón González Férriz conversa con Natalia Fabra sobre los principales retos a los que se enfrenta esta transición energética, pero también abordan otras cuestiones clave del debate actual: ¿cómo se debe reformar el mercado eléctrico?, ¿han sido efectivas las políticas de respuesta a la crisis?, ¿se podría mejorar su diseño?

Todo ello con una clara preocupación por los efectos distributivos negativos que las políticas de lucha contra el cambio climático pueden tener sobra la población y la necesidad de compensarlos.

Escucha el podcast completo aquí.

Assessing the distributional effects of real-time pricing for electricity

Electricity prices are at record highs, imposing large costs for households that vary across the income distribution. This begs the question of how the distributional consequences differ across alternative energy policies. This column compares time-invariant prices in Spain to real-time pricing policies, i.e. prices that reflect the changing costs of meeting electricity demand, using a novel method to estimate household incomes. Switching from time-invariant to real-time pricing gives rise to regressive effects, as low-income households use more electricity during the winter, during which prices are higher. This dominates the fact that high-income households consume disproportionally more electricity during within-day peak hours.

 

You can read the full article of Natalia Fabra and Mar Reguant here.

Hacia un nuevo Orden Mundial de la Energía: España en el marco de la UE

El pasado 27 de septiembre, la Fundación Carlos de Amberes, con el apoyo del Ministerio de Asuntos Exteriores, Unión Europea y Cooperación, organizó la jornada de debate “Hacia un nuevo orden mundial de la energía: España en el marco de la UE”, con el que pretende fomentar el debate de expertos y ciudadanos con el que contribuir a la definición de una política común de la energía, sostenible y segura, que sumen aportaciones susceptibles de ser llevadas a la presidencia española del Consejo de la UE durante el segundo semestre de 2023.

El orden mundial de la energía está sufriendo una crisis sin precedentes, la guerra de Ucrania y la emergencia climática han provocado la necesidad de un cambio urgente.

Este tema es una prioridad para la Unión Europea, que tiene la oportunidad de crear una política energética que impulse su autonomía estratégica y liderazgo en sostenibilidad. Dentro de este marco, España puede convertirse en un referente en energías renovables, como el hidrógeno verde.

Natalia Fabra participó en la sesión “La ruptura del orden existente: motivos y consecuencias”.

Puede ver el vídeo del debate aquí.

Más información aquí.

Infradialogue: How Does the Current Crisis Affect the Future of Global Energy Markets?

The recent rise in energy prices worldwide has sparked a major energy crisis with far-reaching consequences as the Northern Hemisphere prepares for winter. Natural gas spot prices in Asia and Europe have reached levels not seen in the recent decade, and the problem has spread well beyond gas. Global oil prices are rising, China and India are facing record coal costs, and carbon prices in Europe have reached historic highs. As coal- and natural gas-fired generation determines peak electricity prices, power costs are also reaching new highs in many parts of the world. All of these developments call for prompt action by policymakers to mitigate immediate impacts while adapting longer-term strategies for energy sector sustainability.

This discussion will shed light on the following policy questions:

  • How will the record-high oil, gas, and electricity prices in the coming winter affect the energy bills of residential consumers, the competitiveness of businesses, and the performance of energy utilities?
  • How will the ramifications of high energy prices differ across different parts of the world, including middle- and low-income countries?
  • How will high energy prices, especially natural gas prices, affect the global decarbonization agenda?
  • How can policymakers ensure greater resilience of energy markets while addressing energy affordability concerns?

The panel discussion brings together five distinguished academics, energy industry experts, and policy practitioners to discuss the implications of the rapidly unfolding developments in the energy sector on the future of global energy markets:

  • Kaushik Deb, Senior Research Scholar, Center on Global Energy Policy, Columbia University’s School of International and Public Affairs

Kaushik Deb is a Senior Research Scholar at the Center on Global Energy Policy at Columbia University’s School of International and Public Affairs, where his research focuses on policies to achieve a just and efficient energy transition in developing countries, especially the role of oil and gas markets. Prior to joining the Center, Kaushik led the Markets and Industrial Development Program at the King Abdullah Petroleum Studies and Research Center in Riyadh, managing the Center’s engagement with Saudi Arabia’s Ministry of Energy in supporting the development of short and long term strategies for oil and gas markets to achieve the Kingdom’s energy sector objectives.

  • Fernanda Delgado, Corporate Executive Director, IBP – Instituto Brasileiro de Petróleo e Gás

Fernanda Delgado holds the position of Corporate Executive Director of IBP – Instituto Brasileiro de Petróleo e Gás. Professor at FGV in the Post-Graduate Program at the Army Command School, she has Doctorate degree in Energy Planning and Master´s degree in Information Technology. Fernanda has a professional career in relevant companies, both in Brazil and abroad, with four published books on Petropolitics as author.

  • Natalia Fabra, Professor of Economics, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

Natalia Fabra is Professor of Economics at Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. She is a Research Fellow at the Centre for Economic Policy Research and an Associate Member of the Toulouse School of Economics. She belongs to the Economic Advisory Group on Competition Policy (EAGCP) of the European Commission. She obtained her Ph.D. in 2001 at the European University Institute (Florence), under the supervision of Prof. Massimo Motta.

  • Mike Fulwood, Senior Research Fellow, Oxford Institute for Energy Studies (OIES)

Mike Fulwood joined the OIES in October 2017. Mike has over 40 years of experience in the gas industry. Before joining the OIES, Mike worked as a consultant, with Energy Markets between 1997 and 2008 and then with NexantECA as Director, Global Gas & LNG. Before working as consultant, Mike worked for British Gas from 1979, latterly as a Director at British Gas Transco, in charge of the price control review, and prior to that President of British Gas Americas during which time he oversaw many successful acquisitions and projects including the acquisitions of Metrogas (Argentina), NGC (now Dynegy), the Bolivia – Brazil pipeline and Trinidad LNG project.

  • Demetrios Papathanasiou, Global Director, Energy and Extractives Global Practice, World Bank

Demetrios Papathanasiou leads more than 100 professionals at the Global Units of the Energy and Extractives Global Practice of the World Bank. He coordinates the overall strategic direction of the Practice, advances the knowledge and learning agenda for the Bank’s energy and extractives professionals, and oversees corporate reporting, trust funds, and partnerships for the Practice. Dr. Papathanasiou has worked for more than 20 years with the World Bank Group on Energy and Infrastructure in Africa, Latin America, East Europe, and the Balkans, South Asia, East Asia, and the Pacific Islands.

Moderator: Vivien Foster, Chief Economist, Infrastructure Practice Group, World Bank

Our new Newsletter is out!!

The importance of energy for the economy and its systemic effects are now more apparent than ever. This year has witnessed a significant energy crisis in Europe, triggered by the conflict with Russia and deepened by droughts across the continent. Sound policymaking is desperately needed right now. In EnergyEcoLab we keep committed to contributing to improving energy and climate policies in this challenging context through our research and outreach activities.

We are pleased to share with you our 2022 newsletter, which describes some of our most recent research.

[3d-flip-book mode=”fullscreen” id=”3496″][/3d-flip-book]

DOWNLOAD IT!!

Index:

You can take a look at our first, and second Newsletter.

Jornada de Sociedades COSCE 2022

La Confederación de Sociedades Científicas de España (COSCE) celebró la Jornada de Sociedades 2022: “Ciencia para un mundo sostenible”, inaugurada por la Excma. Sra. Diana Morant, ministra de Ciencia e Innovación.

El objetivo de la jornada es poner en perspectiva la aportación más actual de la investigación básica y aplicada a la sostenibilidad del planeta. Contó con ponencias de reconocidos expertos y la
participación de especialistas en una mesa redonda centrada en el reto energético: energías renovables y fusión nuclear.

Natalia Fabra participó en representación de la Asociación de Economía Española con una ponencia titulada “La Sociedad ante el Cambio Climático”.

Puedes ver las diapositivas utilizadas aquí y el vídeo de la charla aquí.

El programa de la jornada se puede ver aquí.

Más información aquí.

Presentation at the LSE Environment Week

On September 19th, 2022, Mateus Souza presented some of his work at the LSE Environment Week. The conference gathered top researchers in the field of environmental and energy economics. The full programme can be found here.

Mateus presented his paper entitled “Energy Efficiency Can Deliver for Climate Policy: Evidence from Machine Learning-Based Targeting.” This is joint work with Peter Christensen, Paul Francisco, Erica Myers, and Hansen Shao. The authors show how a machine-learning based targeting design can help improve the cost-effectiveness of residential energy efficiency programs.

More details can be found in their NBER Working Paper.